The behavior of each firm in the market depends on the structure of the market.
When we say market structure, we often refer to
One of the main market structures we study in economics is the so called “competitive market”. In a competitive market, a single agent (either a firm or a consumer) cannot alter the market price with its sole actions. As a consequence, each of them takes prices as given and select how much to buy or produce. Notice that the consumers and the firms we have studied so far behave in exactly this fashion.
Competitive markets typically exhibit the next characteristics:
Some commodity markets (e.g. the soybeans market) operate close to perfect competition.
A competitive equilibrium indicates a market price at which the amount that the firms would like to produce equals the amount of the good that the consumers would like to buy. We can study this question in the short or in the long run.
In the short run, we assume that the number of firms is fixed. In this case, the competitive equilibrium is given by the price level p* for which the total quantity that consumers are willing to demand (Qd) is the same as the total quantity that firms decide to supply (Qs). That is,
Example: Suppose that there are 100 identical consumers with demand functions for a specific good given by
In addition, let us assume that there are 12 identical firms, each of which has a supply function given by
Adding up the demand of each consumer, we get that the market demand is given by
Adding up the supply of each firm, we get that the market supply is given by
Thus, the short run competitive equilibrium price solves
Thus,
In the long run, we assume that firms have enough time to make entry/exit decisions. We say there is free entry and exit if there are no barriers to enter or exit the industry.
As we explained earlier, if there is free entry, then, in the long run, the firms make zero profits. More precisely, the long run equilibrium consists of a price level (p), a market quantity (Q) and a number of firms (H*) that simultaneously satisfy the next two conditions:
Quantity demanded equals quantity supplied:
Profits are zero for every incumbent firm: for all
.
Notice that the zero profit condition in the long run equilibrium contemplates the fact that the number of firms is determined within the model, by the characteristics of the industry.
Example: Consider an industry where all firms are identical and exhibit a cost function given by:
Moreover, assume that the demand function is given by .
The long-run competitive equilibrium can be obtained as follows. First notice that each firm will optimally select how much to produce solving the next problem
The FOC of this problem is captured by
In addition, we know that, in the long-run, each of them makes zero profits. Thus,
Combining these two results, we get y’=50. Thus, the equilibrium price is p’=15.
To determine how many firms will enter the market, notice that, if p’=15, then the quantity demanded is given by
Since, and each firm produces
, we get that
.
In sum, we have that
We often read in the newspapers about different policies that the government of the US implements to make specific markets more competitive. A natural question arises:
Why are competitive markets desirable?
To answer this question, we need to introduce the concepts of consumer and producer surplus.
Consumer surplus is defined as the difference between consumers’ willingness to pay for a good and the price that they have to actually pay to buy each of the units that they decide to acquire. Graphically, it is the area below the demand curve and above the market price.
Producer surplus, on the other hand, is the difference between the price that the firms get for selling the good and the cost of producing each unit they put on the market. Graphically, it is the area above the supply curve and below the price that producers are charging for the good.
The total surplus of the market is just the sum of consumer and producer surplus. Competitive markets are desirable as they maximize to
Note: see an interactive version of this graph here.
Example: Suppose the demand curve is given by and the supply curve is
. If we calculate the equilibrium price p* and the equilibrium quantity Q* we get
If we draw the demand and supply curves and identify the surpluses graphically, we will see that those are triangles. Using the fact that the area of a triangle is base times height divided by two, then the consumer surplus (CS) is given by:
Similarly, the producer surplus (PS) is given by:
We study an industry in which there is only one firm, a monopoly.
We are interested in situations where this firm has power to set the market price. In this sense we are ruling out what we call contestable markets; these are markets where there is only one firm but if this firm increases the market price, then other firms will surely enter.
There are a few factors that can lead to monopolies:
The problem of the monopoly is as follows. We can let the firm choose the market price (p), and consumers decide how much they want to consume. Or we can model output (y) as its variable of choice. (But not both!) In the latter case, the maximization problem is given by
where is the minimum cost of producing y.
The FOC for the monopoly problem is
where is the marginal revenue,
is the marginal cost,
There is an alternative formulation of the FOC, which helps us to “quantify” the power of the firm to set a “high” market price. First, notice that the MR can be rewritten in an alternative way
where is the price elasticity of demand. Then, the FOC takes the form of
where is called the mark-up.
This representation of the firm’s optimal choice, makes it clear that the monopoly sets the price above its marginal cost. The mark-up measures how much above it is! For this reason, the latter has being used by regulating authorities as a measure of market power.
A priori, the mark-up can either be calculated from price and measures of cost, or from estimates of the elasticity of demand. In practice, a starting point for this calculation can come from the income statement of a firm where you learn profit margins from COGS. (Drawbacks: This is a measure of AC —average costs— not MC —marginal costs—, and may not include all the opportunity costs of the firm.)
Example: Suppose that the monopolist faces a linear demand curve
Its cost is also linear C(y)=cy(with a>c). Thus, the problem of the firm is given by
The FOC is
It follows that
In addition, its mark-up is
## Deadweight Loss of Monopoly |
In general, the monopoly produces less output than firms in a competitive market. Moreover, for some of the extra units that competitive markets would produce people are willing to pay more than the cost of producing them. Thus, a natural question arises: |
Why doesn’t the monopoly increase production? |
- The reason is that to convince people to buy these extra units, the firm needs to lower the market price not only to the new consumers, but also to all of them! |
The deadweight loss (DL) is the difference in Consumer Surplus (CS) and Producer Surplus (PS) between a competitive market and the monopoly. |
Example: As before, suppose that the monopolist faces a linear demand curve |
![]() |
Its cost is also linear ![]() |
The efficient level of production requires ![]() |
![]() |
We obtained earlier that the monopolist optimally produces ![]() ![]() |
In this application, the DL is given by |
![]() |
![]() |
In the previous section we assumed the monopolist charged all the consumers the same market price for the good. There are many situations where this assumption does not hold. That is, situations where this firm sets different prices to different consumers.
In this section, we study three different types of price discrimination:
This is the simplest type of price discrimination. In this case, the monopolist selects a difference price for each consumer. Ideally, this price captures the maximum willingness to pay of the consumer! An example of this type of behavior is probably given by the car dealers.
We showed before that the regular monopolist produces less than the optimal output level —i.e., the one that maximizes social welfare. The reason is that, when it produces more units of the good, it has to lower the price of all previous units in order to sell the extra output. Thus,
What if we allow the monopoly to charge different prices to different consumers?
If we do so, then the monopolist would produce an efficient level of outcome!
There are, however, at least two problems with this type of price discrimination:
This is a non-linear pricing scheme in which the market price depends on the amount of the good that the consumer gets, e.g., discounts by quantity.
The monopolist offers different packages —that differ in number of units and market price— and each consumer “self-selects” into the most attractive one. The purpose of the monopoly is to design the menus so that people self-select into the package that is more convenient for the firm.
Suppose that the monopoly can identify two groups of people with individual demands p1(y1) and p2(y2). These groups depend on observable characteristics, e.g., students vs non-students.
The profit maximization problem is
Thus, the FOC’s for the monopolist are given by
The solution of the problem can be re-written as follows
Thus, the price of the monopolist is larger for the group with the lower elasticity of demand!
The reason is that this group is less sensitive to price changes.
## 4.3 Oligopoly By oligopoly we mean an industry with a few firms that behave strategically. To simplify the exposition, we will mainly consider an industry with only two firms (i.e., a duopoly). |
We will study three types of competition: |
- Cournot: Firms compete by choosing quantities. - Stackelberg: One firm is the leader and the other one is the follower. - Bertrand: Firms compete by choosing prices. |
##### Duopoly of Cournot The model is as follows: |
1. There are two firms in the market that compete in quantities. 2. Each firm selects how much to produce in order to maximize profits, taking as given the decision of the other firm. 3. Firms face a linear demand ![]() ![]() |
Given this information, the profits of these firms are given by |
![]() |
Then, the FOC’s of both firms are |
![]() |
From the FOC’s we derive the reaction function of each firm |
![]() |
These functions indicate how much a firm would like to produce if it expects certain production level from the other firm. |
![]() |
The equilibrium is given by the pair of quantities y1,y2 that solve |
![]() |
This pair requires both, that each firm behaves optimally given what it expects the other firm will do, and that their predictions be correct. In this application, we get |
![]() |
Given this result, the profits of the firms are given by |
![]() |
This is an example of what we call Nash equilibrium! |
Let us next assume that these firms make an initial agreement to maximize joint profits (i.e., they form a cartel).
In this case, they behave as if they were only one (a monopoly)! We obtained before that, with linear demand and cost functions, the solution of the monopoly is
If both firms in the cartel produce the same amount of output, then . It follows that their profits are given by
Thus, the agreement is convenient for the two firms. The reason is that both of them make more money in the cartel than if they were engaged in Cournot competition.
In the stackelberg competition there is a leader and a follower. The model is as follows:
To solve this problem we study first the decision of the follower, and then the one of the leader. (From a mathematical perspective, this technique is called back induction.)
The follower observes the production level of the leader. Then, its profit function is
The FOC for the problem of the follower is given by
Thus, .
The leader knows that the follower selects its production according to
Then, its profit function is given by
The FOC for the leader is given by
It follows that the equilibrium level of production of the leader is
The equilibrium level of production of the follower is
Given these production levels, the profits of the leader are given by
In addition, the profits of the follower are
Thus, the leader makes more money than the follower!
The model is as follows:
The equilibrium of this model is very simple
Notice that this equilibrium is the same as the competitive one! Whenever one of the firms selects a price above c, then the other firm has incentives to choose a price just below the one by the initial firm. The reason is that the good produced by the two firms is identical and thus, by doing so, the second firm can get the whole market. This process repeats till the above condition is reached.
Competition is tougher when firms compete in prices than when they choose quantities!